A recent paper by William White, Chairman of the
Economic Development and Review Committee at the OECD, looks at the balance
between the desirable short-term effects and undesirable long-term effects of
central bank easy money policies. Here we go.
As we all
know, central banks in both advanced and emerging market economies have lowered
interest rates to the zero lower bound (ZLB). On top of that, they have
taken other actions which have caused their balance sheets to swell to
unprecedented levels, loading up with increasingly risky assets. By doing
this, advanced economies have pushed their exchange rates down against the
currencies of the emerging markets. Central banks of emerging market
countries have resisted these moves and have increased their reserves of
foreign exchange to record levels (i.e. by buying advanced market currencies,
they push the price of the currency back up when compared to their own),
swelling their own balance sheets to record levels. When looked at
through historical lenses, all of these central bank machinations are
unprecedented even during the Great Depression; going back to 1954, short and long term rates have never reached such low levels for so long as shown here:
During the
Great Recession, the world's major central banks implemented measures to
restore stability. Even after it appeared that the world economic situation was
stabilizing after the implosion of Lehman Brothers in the fall of 2008, central
banks kept easing largely because it was believed that the duration of the
Great Depression was lengthened because there had been insufficient easing.
As well, the governments of advanced nations were reluctant to use more
fiscal stimulus because of growing concern about sovereign debt levels.
This left central bank policies as the "only game in town",
meaning that interest rates were the only measure that could stimulate
aggregate demand by stimulating the use of credit.
Why are
these low interest rates so dangerous? Let's look at several problems
that are cropping up:
1.) Bond Bubble: Many economists believe that these rates could be creating another asset
bubble that will eventually burst in a most painful manner, this time, in the
world's bond markets. Long term rates in countries that appear to be most
creditworthy could still rise due to fears among the holders of sovereign debt
(counterparty fears) since the required change in government spending habits to
reach fiscal balance are practically impossible.
2.) Consumer Lack of Confidence: Lower
interest rates are used to push consumers to spend now rather than save for
later since there is no reward for saving. Unfortunately, as interest
rates have dropped to unprecedented levels, consumers "smell"
desperation on the part of central bankers and this can (and perhaps has)
depressed consumer confidence and their willingness to spend. Since the
Great Recession, it appears that the public has lost confidence in the ability
of central banks in advanced economies to implement policies that will fix
joblessness, housing price declines and, in some countries, control
inflation.
3.) Low Return on Savings: Lower
rates are a two-edged sword. On one hand, borrowers see their disposable
income increase as interest rates drop. On the other hand, older people
living off the returns from their accumulated assets see their investment
returns plunge, necessitating cutbacks in consumption. When the older
savers cut back spending more than the increase in spending by those who
borrow, overall household consumption levels fall and GDP grows at a lower
rate.
4.) Boom and Bust Cycle Enhancement: Since
the middle 1980s, central banks have been successively more aggressive at both
pre-empting downturns (i.e. after the 1987 stock market crash) or responding to
downturns (i.e. 1991, 2001 and 2008). Each of these actions set the stage
for the next "boom and bust cycle" which was fuelled by easier credit
and expanding debt. Here is a paragraph from the article:
"From
the perspective of this hypothesis, monetary easing after the 1987 stock market
crash contributed to the world wide property boom of the late 1980’s. After it
crashed in turn, the subsequent easing of policy in the AME’s (Advanced Market
Economies) led to massive capital inflows into SEA contributing to the
subsequent Asian crisis in 1997. This crisis was used as justification for a
failure to raise policy rates, in the United States at least, which set the
scene for the excessive leverage employed by LTCM and its subsequent
demise in 1998. The lowering of policy rates in response, even though the unemployment
rate in the AME’s seemed unusually low, led to the stock market bubble that
burst in 2000. Again, vigorous monetary easing resulted, as described above,
which led to a worldwide housing boom. This boom peaked in 2007 in a number of
AME’s, seriously damaging their banking systems as well. However, in other
AME’s, the house price boom continues along with still rising and often record
household debt ratios. This latter phenomena, as well as other signs of rising
inflation and other credit driven imbalances in EME’s, reflects the easy monetary
policies followed worldwide in the aftermath of the crisis."
Apparently,
central bankers are slow to learn from their past mistakes.
5.) Government Debt: Lower
short-term rates are impacting the structure of government debt as governments
rely on shorter and shorter financing. This leaves them very vulnerable
to interest rate risks when rates begin to rise. As well, very low rates
impose a false sense of confidence in the sustainability of government fiscal
strength. Low rates mislead governments into thinking that they have no
need to impose austerity measures until sometime far in the future.
6.) Income Inequality: It is
possible that ultra-low interest rates are in some way responsible for growing
income inequality around the world. On a corporate level, rising profits
have largely been driven by the financial sector; this sector systematically
exploits their knowledge of the system to increase gains from both fees and
market movements. Those individuals who are wealthy enough to have
savings, invest on a leveraged basis, making profits as asset prices rise
during a boom. During a bust, these individuals may lose a small part of
their accumulated wealth but it is those of the middle classes that see their
accumulated assets transferred to the wealthy. Members of the lower
classes see their access to credit disappear along with their jobs as an
economic bust takes hold during a downturn.
7.) Financial Sector Viability: Low
interest rates have threatened the viability of some parts of the financial
sector. Low rates have made money market mutual funds a "mug's
game" as asset returns are often not sufficient to cover operating costs.
Insurance companies have seen declines in returns on their portfolios
which has led to the lowering of dividends, raising of premiums and reduced
payouts to the insured.
From this
posting and William White's analysis, I hope that you can see that central bank
ultra-low interest rate policies have a limited ability to stimulate
"strong, sustainable and balanced growth" in the economy. Low
interest rate policies have a wide range of undesirable effects that show quite
clearly that "...aggressive monetary easing in economic downturns is not
"a free lunch..." no matter what Mr. Bernanke would have us believe.
Good clear explanation. Thank you.
ReplyDeleteIts not that the American people are biologically stupid (and therefore easy targets for the ruinous effects of fiat currency) its that they are ignorant.
ReplyDeleteAs long as American Idol gets more votes than US elections...and some article about doing on Yahoo get's thousands of comments, the downward trend will continue.
Thank you for trying to rectify that.