Updated February 2015
In the early days of my career in the late 1970s and early 1980s, one thing that employees could count on was getting a raise that would include a cost of living allowance or COLA. That way, we had some assurance that our compensation was keeping up with increases in what we were spending to live. A paper by Lawrence Mishel and Kar-Fai Gee gives us some insight into the conundrum that faces workers in America. While labour productivity increased over the four decades from 1973 to 2011, the same cannot be said for gains in real wages, that is, wages that are corrected for increases in the cost of living.
In the early days of my career in the late 1970s and early 1980s, one thing that employees could count on was getting a raise that would include a cost of living allowance or COLA. That way, we had some assurance that our compensation was keeping up with increases in what we were spending to live. A paper by Lawrence Mishel and Kar-Fai Gee gives us some insight into the conundrum that faces workers in America. While labour productivity increased over the four decades from 1973 to 2011, the same cannot be said for gains in real wages, that is, wages that are corrected for increases in the cost of living.
The median wage represents the wage
earned by a worker at the midpoint between the highest and lowest paid worker.
Using median values rather than average values avoids the problem that
can occur when wages change only at the top and bottom of the distribution.
Over the period from 1973 to 2011, the long-term growth in the median
real compensation, which includes all benefits plus salary and wages, has been
very low, averaging only 4 percent over the four decades as shown on this
graph:
Over the period, the median hourly
compensation has risen from $18.08 (in 2011 dollars) in 1973 to $20.01 in 2011,
an average annual increase of 0.27 percent per year. The graph shows that
the real median compensation level was pretty stagnant from 1973 to 1992 when
it increased rather sharply until 2003 and then remained stagnant thereafter.
In fact, in 2011, the real median compensation fell by 2.5 percent; this
in a year when the economy was in full recovery mode!
Now, let's compare what happened to
the average and median real hourly compensation, again, keeping in mind that
average compensation is affected by changes in compensation at the top and
bottom of the entire distribution (i.e. if wages increase at the top, the
average will increase but most workers may still have seen little increase in
compensation):
Real average compensation has risen
from $25.54 (in 2011 dollars) in 1973 to $35.05 in 2011 which results in an
annual growth rate of 0.87 percent, just over three times the growth rate of
the median. The faster growth in the average means that earning
inequality is growing and that the highest paid workers are seeing their compensation
rise at rates much higher than among their lesser paid peers as you can see on
this graph:
The share of all wages paid to the
top one percent of earners has nearly doubled from 1973 to 2010; in 1973, the
top earners received 6.8 percent of all wages paid. By 2010, this had
increased to 12.9 percent of all wages paid. In fact, the top 0.1 percent
of earners received 4.7 percent of all wages paid in 2010, up from 1.5 percent
in 1979. This is in sharp contrast to the earnings of the bottom 90 percent
of earners who saw their wages in 2010 being only 115 percent of their wages
way back in 1979!
Now, let's switch gears for a
minute. Let's look at how productive America's workers have been.
Labour productivity is defined as the output produced on an hourly basis
by an average worker and is measured as real GDP per hour worked as shown on this graph:
Between the first quarter of 1973
and the first quarter of 2011, real output per hour rose from 51.26 to 104.03,
an increase of 102.9 percent. In real dollar terms, labour productivity
grew from $33.68 (in 2011 dollars) in 1973 to $60.77 in 2011, an average
increase of 1.56 percent per year. The real growth rate in worker productivity
is 5.8 times the growth rate in median real hourly compensation!
Here is a graph showing the labour share which
is defined as the share of total nominal worker compensation in nominal GDP:
Between 1974 and 2011, labour's
share of GDP fell from 67.7 percent to 62.2 percent, the lowest level on record looking back to 1950. Note that during the 1980s and early 1990s, labour's share
was pretty consistent, rising between 1997 and 2001 when it hit 66.4 percent.
From there, it began its downhill slide to 62.2 percent as noted above.
What does all of this mean? It
means that, on average, workers in America have benefitted very, very little
from growth in labour productivity (for which they are largely responsible) in terms of real wage growth and that their share of the economy has declined to levels not seen going back six decades. Sadly, this is a situation
that has become worse over time. The gap between median wage and
productivity growth was 0.84 percentage points per year between 1995 and has
increased to 1.84 percentage points per year between 2000 and 2011.
There has been a dramatic increase of redistribution of income from labour to
capital as a share of America's total income, largely related to these factors:
1.) de-unionization.
2.) globalization.
3.) high trade deficits.
4.) high unemployment.
5.) higher levels of investment in
short-lived capital assets including information and communication technologies
that require frequent updating and replacement.
The sluggish increase in the level
of real median worker compensation and the contrasting substantial increase in
worker productivity speaks to the "new way of doing business in
America". As the Great Recession showed, workers are deemed necessary
only because they are critical to increasing output and are quickly ushered to the door when times get tough.
This is extremely interesting material, for it is the first time I have seen productivity and wages linked.
ReplyDeleteI can only imagine the time it took you to comprise this material, compared to the time it took me to read it.
I hope this article gets a lot of distribution.
Don Levit
Thanks Don.
DeleteI don't understand why "higher levels of investment in short-lived capital assets" would contribute to the redistribution of income to capital.
ReplyDeleteMarvelous article! How the fruits of labor are divided is important. This includes not just the wage deserved by a common laborer, but how much those in management, top CEO's, and those that can't, or choose not to work, receive. While we have become far more efficient in producing goods, all people should in their lifetime contribute to the good of society and the economic pie.
ReplyDeleteChoosing not to work and live off the labor of others is theft. In principle, for any nation seeking fairness and equal opportunity for its people to grow and prosper inequality is an issue. Today wage stagnation has in part contributed to the financial crisis. The article below delves into this difficult problem.
http://brucewilds.blogspot.com/2013/04/society-must-better-divide-labor.html
Great article!! One of the few Americans still concerned with fighting for the workers. I'd like to see every executive living in the US provide for their family and lifestyle on $8.25/hr or even $15/hr. Good Luck! Oh and lets see them find a new job while being worked to death. I am still condused as to how the minimum wage is not an anti-trust infringement. The minimum wage is basically pricing fixing the labor market, with the government as the controller and companies following suit. The American consumer is just as much at fault, buying crap in exchange for their hard earned work money. Rendering a vicious cycle to $0.00. As the US citizens are becoming wiser through this decades long experience, the worker will be relevant again. Abraham Lincoln is quoted as saying "A society that does not value work/laor, is a society that is failing"
ReplyDelete"It means that, on average, workers in America have benefitted very, very little from growth in labour productivity (for which they are largely responsible)"
ReplyDeleteIncreases in worker productivity have come largely from investments in capital and technology. What exactly have workers done to improve their productivity? The general answer is to improve their (related) education and training. Do you really think this has been happening? Where it does happen, it is usually the company that pays for it and once trained, workers generally expect higher pay or they jump ship. This does not help productivity.
There is an adversarial relationship between workers and management. The only way to survive amidst globalized competition is for workers and management to function as a team and our current capital ownership model does not allow for that.