An analysis by Josh Bivens at the Center on
Budget and Policy Priorities looks at the connection between wages and
inflation. The strong link between interest rates and price inflation is
through the mechanism of wage increases which are spurred by tightness in the
labor market. By increasing short-term interest rates, the pace of
economic activity is lowered, reducing the pace of declines in unemployment
which reduces the ability of workers' to bargain for higher wages which, in
turn, reduces the pressure on inflation. Mr. Bivens observes that, since
wage inflation and not slackness in the labor market is the most significant intermediate
link between interest rate increases and lower price inflation, the brilliant
minds at the Federal Reserve should focus on wage inflation as an indicator of
where interest rates should head. With the Federal Reserve contemplating
a move toward tightening after their prolonged experiment with zero interest
rates because of improvements in the headline unemployment rate, perhaps they need to take a closer look at what has happened to nominal
wages to determine their future policies.
As has become apparent,
the traditional measures of economic health, particularly the headline U-3
unemployment rate have become particularly useless indicator of economic health
since the labor force participation rate, at 62.5 percent, is depressed to
levels not seen since the late 1970s as shown on this graph:
Other economic measures
like estimates of the natural rate of unemployment which is the rate below
which inflationary pressures will increase are subject to large margins of
error and are not suitable for determining monetary policies.
As we've noted, since
late 2010, the unemployment rate has fallen steadily yet, inflation has
remained tame as shown on this graph:
This is telling us that
even though unemployment dropped from 10 percent in 2010 to approximately 5.5.
percent in mid-2015, inflation has not reared its ugly, frightening (to central
bankers) head. Conventional wisdom would tell us that inflation should be
much higher than it is given that unemployment has nearly halved and that there
should be significant upward pressure on wages. Unfortunately for those
of us who work for a living, this graph that shows what has happened to
nominal wages and unemployment since 2006 is particularly sobering:
Economists like to use
the Phillips curve which plots the percentage
change in inflation (or nominal wages since the two are closely connected to
each other) against the level of unemployment which looks like this for the
1960s:
As you can see, at high
levels of unemployment, inflation/wage increases are low. In the 1960s,
as the economy moved from 6.5 percent unemployment to 5.5 percent unemployment,
inflation/wages rose by a less than one-half percent. When the economy
moved from 4 percent unemployment to 3.5 percent unemployment, inflation/wages
rose by more than a percent. As unemployment decreases, inflation/wage
increases begin to rise at a faster rate. This is not the case now; as
the graph above shows, at 5.5 percent unemployment, the inflation rate/rate of
nominal average wage increases is far, far lower than most economists would predict
using the Phillips curve.
Now, let's switch gears
and look at another measure of economic health, productivity, a measure that
will help us set a wage target. First, here's a rule of thumb from the
paper:
"...as long as
nominal wages are growing at or beneath the rate of productivity growth, then
labor costs are putting no upward pressure on prices at all. This concept is
embodied in unit labor costs, i.e., the unit of compensation per unit of
productivity. If real wages and productivity accelerate by equal amounts (in
percentage terms), there is no increase in unit labor costs and no pressure on
prices from wage growth, as more efficient production (faster productivity
growth) has “absorbed” the wage increase such that it does not need to be
passed through to prices.
For small magnitudes, the
change in unit labor costs can be approximated as the percentage change in
hourly pay minus the percentage change in productivity. And this change is what
the Fed is hoping to keep running below its target rate of overall price
inflation. So long as unit labor costs are rising at less than 2 percent, they
are not putting upward pressure on the price inflation target."
Obviously, changes in
worker compensation are closely connected to the growth rate of productivity.
Here is a graph showing the total growth in net economy-wide average
annual changes in productivity over 12, 24 and 60 month-long cycles between
1995 and 2014:
Productivity growth over
the cycle between 2001 and 2007 averaged 2.1 percent and over the four cycles
between 1973 and 2007, it averaged 1.5 percent. The author feels that
range of 1.5 to 2.0 percent is reasonable. Therefore, if we sum
changes in productivity at 1.5 percent to 2.0 percent and accompany it
with inflation at 2.0 percent (the Federal Reserve's target rate), then hourly
compensation growth of between 3.5 and 4.0 percent should not cause a problem.
That said, as shown on this graph, the year-over-year change in nominal
average hourly earnings of American workers since 2007 has been well below the
minimum wage-growth target (shaded grey):
As you can see, hourly
wage growth has been between 1.5 and 2.5 percent since 2009, well below the
wage-growth target. This extremely low level of wage growth makes us
wonder why inflation hasn't been even lower than it is. Here's the fly in
the ointment:
All of the growth in
prices since the second quarter of 2009 can be accounted for by rising profits
(light blue bars) due to increases in markups over costs. Unit labor
costs have been flat and all other costs have actually declined but unit
profits on a pre-tax basis have increased by 7.6 percent annually. This
growth in unit profits are responsible for 64 percent of the rise in prices
since the last business cycle peak in the last quarter of 2007.
This
is why the labor share of corporate sector income has done this since the early
1980s:
With
nominal wage growth of 4 percent, it would take until 2029 to attain the
pre-Great Recession labor share of corporate sector income of 79.4 percent in
Q4 2007. Using the same 2 percent inflation numbers and 1.5 percent trend
productivity growth as before, with nominal wage growth of 4.5 percent, it
will take until 2022 and with 5 percent nominal wage growth, it will
take until 2019 to attain the pre-Great Recession labor share of profits as
shown on this graphic:
Despite the
fact that we are now seven years past the trough of the Great Recession, we are
still seeing very little improvement in the wages of American workers.
Wages are still growing at levels that are well below
the non-inflationary wage-growth target levels of between 3.5 and 4.0
percent. Rather than sharing the benefits gleaned from increasing worker
productivity since the Great Recession, Corporate America is choosing to
pad its bottom line, explaining why inflationary pressures have been far lower than we would normally expect.
The funny thing is Gen. Y are willing to work for low wages...
ReplyDelete"Rather than sharing the benefits gleaned from increasing worker productivity since the Great Recession, Corporate America is choosing to pad its bottom line..."
ReplyDeleteCorporate America is sharing its profits...with politicians. Politicians write laws that benefit corporations and corporations shovel money to politicians in the form a campaign contributions. The battle over the Ex-Im Bank is a recent, fabulous example, in which famous "social justice warrior" pols somehow found a reason to reauthorize that great geyser of crony capitalism, the Bank.
And it all comes down to too much power held by the national government. This is not a new problem:
"If the government is to tell big business men how to run their business, then don't you see that big business men have to get closer to the government even than they are now? Don't you see that they must capture the government, in order not to be restrained too much by it? Must capture the government? They have already captured it"
Woodrow Wilson, 1913
Both parties have been truly captured by businesses and unions. leaving the average person to twist in the wind.
A big problem with jobs is the more they pay the greater the incentive becomes to find a way to make them more efficient and reduce the number of workers preforming them. Unemployment is a world wide problem. In developed countries it appears to be structural and caused by a lack of demand. Bad tax policies and government interference in the economy often favoring large businesses have added to the problem.
ReplyDeleteUnemployment tears at the fabric of society as many of the unemployed become disheartened. Overtime their skills tend to become "rusty" and obsolete. This often leads to problems with debt and homelessness that can cause the unemployed to fall into the vicious circle of poverty. This means that when the economy recovers these individuals may not fit the job vacancies that are created. The article below looks into the cultural damage this reeks.
http://brucewilds.blogspot.com/2013/01/unemployment-and-its-effect-on-culture.html